Serious investment thinking that doesn’t take itself too seriously.

HOME

LOGIN

ABOUT THE CURIOUS INVESTOR GROUP

SUBSCRIBE

SIGN UP TO THE WEEKLY

PARTNERS

TESTIMONIALS

CONTRIBUTORS

CONTACT US

MAGAZINE ARCHIVE

PRIVACY POLICY

SEARCH

-- CATEGORIES --

GREEN CHRONICLE

PODCASTS

THE AGENT

ALTERNATIVE ASSETS

THE ANALYST

THE ARCHITECT

ASTROPHYSIST

THE AUCTIONEER

THE ECONOMIST

EDITORIAL NOTES

FACE TO FACE

THE FARMER

THE FUND MANAGER

THE GUEST ESSAY

THE HEAD HUNTER

HEAD OF RESEARCH

THE HISTORIAN

INVESTORS NOTEBOOK

THE MACRO VIEW

POLITICAL INSIDER

THE PROFESSOR

PROP NOTES

RESIDENTIAL INVESTOR

TECHNOLOGY

UNCORKED

Establishing Large Conservation Areas in Pakistan

by | Jul 23, 2018

The Analyst

Establishing Large Conservation Areas in Pakistan

by | Jul 23, 2018

Pakistan’s valuable ecosystems are vulnerable to unsustainable use and destruction. Like many developing countries, Pakistan is exposed to “the catastrophic convergence of postcolonial militarisation and ethnic fragmentation,” and may soon be “collapsing under internationally brokered debt and climate change,” which may transform vulnerable ecosystems into “abattoirs of extinction” (New Philosopher, 2016).

Poorer communities living near important ecosystems have high discount rates, causing them to prioritise subsistence (by way of degrading biodiversity) over sustainable living. This threat is amplified by the country’s timber, agricultural, mining and hydropower industries’ interest in environmental destruction.

These land use decisions solely represent nature’s direct consumptive value, and fail to account for other aspects of biodiversity’s value:

  1. Nature’s direct non-consumptive value, such as sustainable tourism, which consumes biodiversity without depleting it.
  2. Indirect use value: leaving ecosystems intact yields positive externalities spanning improved equity, food security and climate change resilience (EPI, 2018).
  3. Option values, which refer to the utility available from using nature in the future.
  4. Nature’s non-use value: the inherent worth of ecosystems (Kontoleon, 2017).

Consequently, biodiverse ecosystems will be undervalued and overexploited with respect to their “true worth”, making habitat loss the consequence of a series of market failures that mandate corrective intervention. Large conservation areas (LCAs) are one such remedial measure.

LCAs represent conservationists’ response to the limited benefits offered by smaller protected areas (PAs), which often cannot always appreciably counteract habitat fragmentation and encourage environmental recovery. Achim Steiner (IUCN’s former Director General)’s argument that “In the past they (small PAs) have been seen as islands of protection in an ocean of destruction. We need to learn to look on them as building blocks of biodiversity, with their benefits extending far beyond their physical boundaries” (Steiner, 2003). LCAs fulfil demands for “landscape-scale” conservation and afford ecosystems the space required for meaningful recovery. This is particularly important in Pakistan: as the country 7th most-affected by climate change since 1997 (Eckstein, Künzel, & Schäfer, 2017), protected flora and fauna will require additional space to respond to habitat shifts induced by climate change. This has been recognised by the Pakistani government: in its 2009 Biodiversity Action Plan, it recommended integrating PAs into regional land-use planning in order to maximise the coverage they provide (Pakistan Environment Ministry, 2009).

The diffuse effects of LCAs produce economic gains for extractive industries. For example, protecting biodiverse territorial waters allows fish stocks to reproduce safely, which makes fishing more sustainable and profitable (Roberts, 2012). Economic benefits from direct use also include tourism revenue. As LCAs accelerate environmental recovery, the existence value of the biodiversity they protect rises with time.

This conception of LCAs frames conservation as a model for rational resource use, which places it in competition with other land use options. This makes choosing to establish an LCA a political choice. Consequently, the manner of their establishment and management is of vital concern for policymakers.

Species-oriented methods require surveys to be conducted in prospective LCAs in order to gauge an ecosystem’s health and conservation value. Species-based metrics can justify expanding existing LCAs: for example, incorporating newly-discovered migration corridors into existing LCAs could have outsized conservation value for endangered species such as snow leopards and Himalayan brown bears (Zakaria, 2018).

Neoliberal conservation methods, based on strongly-defined property rights and turning ecosystems into something “that capital can see,” (Robertson, 2006), comprise the alternative approach to LCA inception. These methods, pioneered by influential conservationist Tony Juniper (Juniper, 2013), are considered to represent a “modern” approach to conservation. One neoliberal conservation model is a Market-Based Instrument (MBI), which uses a set of criteria, such a given piece of land’s diversity of flora and fauna or the different habitats enclosed by it, to award an ecosystem a money value.

However, neoliberal approaches to conservation have been widely criticised for being conceptually flawed, as living environments are too complex, multi-layered and in flux to be commodified by ad-hoc valuation systems (Robertson, 2006). Turning ecosystems into temporally and spatially transferable “isolated biodiversity units” (Apostolopolou & Adams, 2015) deprives them of any locational specificity, resulting in an inability to overcome the “perils” of habitat fragmentation (Adams, 2004). Awarding locals property rights exposes their land to purchase by richer actors (Igoe & Brockington, 2007). In Pakistan, poor local communities would simultaneously struggle to afford to keep their land and strongly rely on it. Land prices would represent the cost of ecosystems’ destruction, implying that biodiversity loss is inevitable (Apostolopolou & Adams, 2015).

Even if these methods worked, they would be unusable in Pakistan: rural areas are typified by usufruct property rights, which nullifies the applicability of models based on private property (Pakistan Environment Ministry, 2009).

This indicates that the state is best placed to establish Pakistan’s LCAs. Governments establishment “represents … a nationalisation of private rights in land,” implying that “the benefits of nature should accrue to the people in general, rather than to private landholders” (Adams, 2004).

There appears to be a tradeoff between having LCAs and displacing local communities. However, in . Against Extinction, (Adams, 2004) argues that “the very idea that there is something called ‘nature’ or ‘the environment’ as a category that is logically separate from humanity itself is a product of centuries of post-enlightenment thinking.”

This tradeoff assumes that nature needs saving from destructive local communities. Locals’ proximity to vital habitats results in them being considered the primary threat to them (Igoe and Brockington, 2007). However, this is far from the case in Pakistan, where locals founded Musk Deer National Park, established a protected area near Nanga Parbat (Zakaria, 2018) and manage Torghar National Park on former tribal land.

The objectives of LCAs in such areas must allow traditional land use patterns serve as the foundation for conservation (Pakistan Environment Ministry, 2009). This approach would preserve contiguous ecosystems of value alongside buffer zones where local communities can continue to use natural resources more sustainably. Buffer zones can also be used to knit together smaller PAs to form de facto LCAs servicing bionetworks and rural communities (Western & Pearl, 1990).

This apparent compromise highlights the nature of environmental protection in developing countries: competing interests such as urban sprawl and population growth make achieving vital conservation outcomes is necessarily opportunistic. This is reflected by the necessity of varying management arrangements in Pakistan’s PAs. However, this does not in any way devalue the sustainable development results that LCAs deliver.

About Aadil Siddiqi

About Aadil Siddiqi

Aadil is a second-year land economist at the University of Cambridge and a Cambridge Trust Scholar. He also serves as the Trinity Hall JCR's Green, Ethics and Charities Officer and is on the Committee of the newly-formed Cambridge University Marine Conservation Society. Aadil's primary interests revolve around issues of sustainability, conservation, economic development and the linkages between them. He is from Karachi.

INVESTOR'S NOTEBOOK

Smart people from around the world share their thoughts

READ MORE >

THE MACRO VIEW

Recent financial news and how it connects across all asset classes

READ MORE >

TECHNOLOGY

Fintech, proptech and what it all means

READ MORE >

PODCASTS

Engaging conversations with strategic thinkers

READ MORE >

THE ARCHITECT

Some of the profession’s best minds

READ MORE >

RESIDENTIAL ADVISOR

Making money from residential property investment

READ MORE >

THE PROFESSOR

Analysis and opinion from the academic sphere

READ MORE >

FACE-TO-FACE

In-depth interviews with leading figures in the real estate/investment world.

READ MORE >